Deficit
Budgeting In Zambia: A Worrisome Return to Unsustainable Debts?
By: Dr Mbita Chitala ; Executive Director – Zambia
Research Foundation
In fiscal
2014, Finance Minister Alexander Bwalya Chikwanda has announced that our national budget of
K42,682,030,000 will be partly funded by a huge deficit of K10,516,870,000 in
addition to domestic revenue of K29,538,540,000 and hoped for grants from
donors of K2,636,630,000.
It should be
noted that the projected GDP of Zambia in 2014 will be K135,744,646,000
according to the MTEFF, and our 2014
budget will be K42,682,030,000 which is
30.7% of our GDP
What observers
see as worrisome is the impact of the huge deficit financing that represents
24.6% of the budget and 7.2% of GDP on the economy of Zambia. Does this mean a
return to unsustainable borrowings where the country joined the HIPC group of
counties or it is the beginning of growth of our economy.
The management of the public debt, and its growth is currently a controversial
issue in the debate over responsible fiscal policy. There is a
continuing controversy as to whether governments should entertain deficit
financing. The simple answer is that deficit financing of any national budget
can be either good or bad depending on how it is managed.
What is Deficit Financing/spending?
Deficit
financing is when a government spends in excess of tax receipts. In order to
fill the gap of their deficit budgets, governments usually borrow or print
money. In Zambia, the Bank of Zambia on behalf of government will issue
Treasury Bills and Bonds which will be bought through open market operations. Furthermore,
the government can also borrow from other governments, multilateral
institutions as well as from private money market institutions or simply print
currency to fill the gap.
Public Debt in Zambia
Deficit
financing is part of the problem of public debt management. In the period from
1978 up to 2004, Zambia’s debt burden increased at a rapid rate because of
borrowings. The public debt for Zambia has been growing exponentially.
In 1978,
external debt stood at US$999.5 million reaching US$3.3 billion in 1980 and
further increasing to more than US$7.2 billion in 1990. The external public
debt went down during the early 1990s reaching US$3.7 Billion in1992 but climbed back to more than US$7 billion by
the end of 1996 and reaching US$7.2 Billion in 2004.
On the other hand, domestic debt stock in 1978
was a mere US$378.5 million. In 2003, it had risen to ZMK3.9 Trillion while in
2004, it stood at Zambian Kwacha 5.5 Trillion. In 2011, Zambia’s internal debt
was K13.122 billion while as at September 2013, the internal debt has jumped to
an all time high of K17.8 billion and the end year 2013 figures will certainly
be higher.
The total
external debt alone represented over 120 percent of Zambia’s Gross Domestic
Product (GDP) in 2003. The external debt service of US$462 million in 2003
represented about 11 percent of GDP, 15.4 percent of total exports, about three
times the national education budget and about four times the health budget.
Indeed, the projected debt service without any debt relief agreement with the
major creditors in 2004 and 2005 would have been US$470 Million and US$475
Million representing 8.8 percent and 8.3
percent of Zambia ’s
GDP, respectively.
However,
because of various debt cancellations and relief, the external debt service was
reduced to ZMK229 billion and ZMK152 billion in 2003 and in 2004 respectively.
President Mwanawasa left a legacy of a
sustained public debt management after inheriting an unsustainable debt which in 2005
reached $7.2 billion. After successful negotiations with all creditor
organizations (multilateral institutions, Paris Club and London Club), Zambia
was able to enjoy the debt relief under HIPC which saw our external debt reduce
to about $500,000,000 in 2007.
Soon after the demise of Mwanawasa, the administration
of President Banda started borrowing. In 2009, the total public debt was
K15,620,570,000 which was 24.17% of GDP and comprised of K9,502,060,000
domestic debt and K6,118,510,000 external debt. The public debt continued
increasing and in 2011, the total public debt rose to K21, 310, 830,00
(K13,122,410,000 domestic debt and K8,188,430,000 external debt).
Zambia’s public debt has continued to rise
after the PF took over government. As at 31 December, 2012, Zambia’s external
outstanding debt was $3,068,133,946.13 of which $2,944,687,444.08 was debt outstanding
and the arrears comprised $78,540,177.05 of principal and $44,906,325.00 of
interest. The consolidated domestic debt for 2012 is not yet available although
an additional K1, 324.3 billion had been budgeted for borrowing in 2013. And
for the 2014, the government plans to run another budget deficit by borrowing
K10, 516,870,000 or 24.6 % of the budget or 7.5% of GDP.
The above policy regime is bound to not only
increase our total indebtedness but may start creating another unwarranted debt
overhang which will not be sustainable. A time after borrowing comes when the
burden of annual repayments of loans and interest as percentage of current
receipts will become unpayable when they fall due. In the current situation, the government has
been failing to redeem the public debt when it falls due and have tended to
accumulate expenditure arrears in both the domestic debt and the external debt.
The challenge the government faces is on
expenditure management, to devise a domestic and external debt management
strategy that will ensure that the high debt stock and rising debt service
burden shall not adversely impact on the country’s economic growth. Unless the
government uses the debt so acquired prudently in programs that add to our GDP,
the country may get back to the HIPC condition where our country would lose its
credit worthiness and become a pariah in the world of civilized nations.
However as already stated, deficit financing
by governments can be both good and progressive or bad and retrogressive
depending on how the contracted debt is managed.
Arguments against Deficit Financing
Many critics
of the PF government have objected to deficit financing arguing that it is bad
policy. These fiscal conservatives contend that a government should always run
a balanced budget and if need be, it should have a surplus budget to pay down
any outstanding debt. This position has its origin from Adam Smith (1723-90)
and was further advocated by Milton Friedman (1912-2006) of the Chicago School
of Economics. This view is also associated with the gold standard where all
currencies were fixed against gold. The idea is that a government must spend
what it has.
Some critics have not only faulted state
borrowing especially deficit financing for being inflationary, but also
contended that it overburdened future generations. David Hume (1771-1776) was
one of the first scholars to address the subject and criticized the idea of
deficit financing. Adam Smith devoted
forty pages of his work “The Wealth of Nations” criticizing the principle of
deficit financing. David Ricardo (1951) also condemned public debt creation by
governments and noted that this principle tended to destroy capital. This
criticism was extended further by J.S. Mill (1915) who viewed the public debt
as a double burden which had to be opposed.
Generally, all these classical scholars
opposed the idea of public debt creation and ascribed to the need for states to
adhere to balanced budgets. These protagonists based their approach on the
principle of strictly controlling growth in the money supply and argued that
this approach was the one sufficient and essential condition for the control of
inflation.
The basic flaw of this monetarism was
revealed in practice, not because it was ineffective in bringing down
inflation, but because it could only do so by means of strangling the real
productive economy, and then could not prevent a recurrence of inflation in the
event of a sustained revival of growth.
Other critics
contend that deficit financing is inflationary and this is a bad thing.
Governments normally print money to pay off debts when they fall due and
thereby increase money supply which fuels inflation. This view is criticized by
Keynesians who argue that deficit financing may not be the only factor that can
be inflationally. There are other factors such as supply side shocks. An
example for this is an oil crisis. Inflation
therefore depends on monetary policy.
Furthermore, deficit financing is opposed as
it is seen as an unnecessary way of creating public debt. In the case of
Zambia, the government will borrow by using the Bank of Zambia to sell treasury
bills and bonds as well as compel Bank of Zambia to printing money. The
government also plans to borrow from foreign governments such as China as well
as multilateral institutions such as the World Bank, IMF, ADB and from the Euro
bond market. The burden of this debt on Zambia shall be the principal and the
interest which shall be paid to holders of treasury bills and bonds and other promissory
notes as well as to the external debt to be contracted. This ostensibly will
restrict the government from being able to cut taxes or raise its expenditure.
A further
argument against deficit financing is that spending today will require
increased taxation of citizens in future to pay the debt. It is contended that
it is unfair to burden future generations with suffocating debt obligations.
Some political
economists also believe that government deficit financing takes away loanable
funds from banks and thus push up interest rates. The high interest rates tend
to crowd out or discourage private investment cancelling the so called fiscal
stimulus and impeding growth of the economy.
Most observers agree that for domestic debt,
the borrowing should not create unnecessary and costly distortions in the
economy. If the domestic debt affects the economy adversely through high
interest rates, it may in turn lead to a slow down on economic growth. The central point is that whereas borrowing
domestically is healthy, it must be within limits because excessive borrowing
could be distortionary and it would tend to slow capital formation.
Furthermore, a
large public debt can create adverse effects on national income. A large
government debt can clearly be detrimental to long run economic growth. First,
as the debt accumulates, more and more private capital is displaced resulting
in lower national output. Secondly, additional taxes are levied to pay interest
on rising debt stock resulting in inefficiencies which in turn leads to lower
output. Taking the two together, output and consumption will grow slowly than
they would had there been no large government debt and deficit.
Arguments for Deficit Financing
The arguments for deficit financing are
espoused by those who advocate the administrative control of prices and wages
as the most appropriate means of controlling inflation. John Maynard Keynes
(1936) in his seminal work “The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and
Money” debunked the classical view that low levels of demand in an economy were
self-correcting.
Keynes advocated that when an economy was in
or likely to go into recession, the central government must engage in deficit
spending. This doctrine meant that a government could borrow money to spend on
public works and other public goods. In so doing, the government would expand
overall demand. Keynes further advocated expansionary monetary and fiscal
policies, meaning, the use of expanding money supply and lowering taxes to
stimulate economic activity.
Broadly speaking, Keynes advocated the
management of demand to maintain full employment in the economy. Said
differently, John Maynard Keynes (1883-1946) argued that that deficit
financing is desirable and necessary. A country should run deficits when there
is recession to compensate for the shortfall in aggregate demand. When an
economy has high unemployment, an increase in government purchases creates a
market for business output, creating more money in people’s pockets and
encouraging increases in consumer spending. This multiplier effect further
increases demand for goods and services and raises the GDP and employment
opportunities. Deficit financing works as a stimulus in an economy and will
encourage companies to invest more capital and in the process they will be
assured with reaping high profits.
It is
important to note, however, that deficit financing can stimulate demand if the government’s
deficit is spent on such things as capital items that will in turn increase
potential output in the long run
The Post
Keynesians such as the Chartalists even go further and contend that deficit
spending money is what is taxed at the end.
A government cannot bust its budget as a national budget is simply an
account of national spending priorities.
Furthermore,
it is argued that deficit financing is necessary for monetary expansion in an
expanding economy such as has been the case for Zambia for the last ten years.
If the economy grows as it has been at more than 7% of GDP annually, the money
supply should also grow. And this can only be accomplished by deficit
financing. If this is not done, it may lead to a credit bubble and a financial
crisis. Deficit financing is acceptable but it depends on the level of GDP
growth.
The Neo- Monetarist Argument
The Keynesian advocacy of deficit financing
has however been opposed by the so called neo-monetarists who take the view
that the control of inflation in an economy is more important than reducing
unemployment. This view is closely identified with the ideas of the Nobel
Prize-winning Professor Milton Friedman who also greatly influenced the now
failed Structural Adjustment Policies of the World Bank and the IMF.
The neo-monetarists advocate tight monetary
and fiscal policies and the balancing of state budgets. They warn of the future
consequences of debt accumulation and its burden upon later generations.
Neo-monetarists contend that debt finance places an unfair burden on future
generations, firstly, by reduced capital formation when resources shift from
the private sector to the public as occurs when the state borrows domestically.
Secondly, by sadling future generations with an obligation to service the
foreign debt.
The weakness of the neo-monetarist conception
is that they confuse the tasks at hand. The question is not whether a
government can repay the debt, because public debt and the economic management
are a continuing undertaking. When a debt issue matures, it is paid off as the
necessary funds are obtained by issuing new obligations. The issue rather is
how interest service will affect the economy and how outstanding debt enters
into the liquidity structure of the economy.
World
Experience
The
reality on the ground is that all countries incur public debt of one type or
another purely on the basis of necessity. For instance, over 80 per cent of
Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) governments borrowing
was in the form of marketable instruments such as government bonds and treasury
bills. On average, since the year 2000, OECD countries have been running budget
deficits of around 4 per cent of GDP. Even prudent Asian governments, including
Japan ,
have been running budget deficits of an estimated 3 per cent per annum during
the decade 1980-90. The OECD predicted that by 2008, its members would be
sitting on central government debts totaling 86 per cent of their combined
Gross Domestic Product (GDP).
This situation repeats itself in almost all
developing countries. For instance, in the United States in the 1950s
and 1960s, the country’s debt exceeded its GDP. However, this is the time the
USA experienced long prosperity. President Obama’s stimulus program in the USA
that has been used to defeat the recession is anchored on huge government deficit spending.
For a country
to engage in deficit financing, it means that the private sector is in surplus.
In other words, deficit spending will permit the private sector to accumulate
net worth. This is why all governments run budget deficits.
Deficit financing: Good or bad
The majority
of economists would agree that if a government borrows in order to deal with a
recession or spends on public investment on infrastructure, education, public
health, on public goods that will advance capital accumulation, then such
deficit financing is bearable, beneficial and even necessary. If on the other
hand deficit financing is for current consumption such as wages and so on, this
would tend to suffocate the economy.
The challenge
for Zambia is to ensure that the debts being contracted by the PF government
are expended on programs that will allow
Zambia accumulate investable surpluses for capital accumulation and expanded
reproduction. What is necessary is therefore to ensure that government
expenditures are productive in the sense that they should contribute to the
growth of national income.
Furthermore,
the government may wish to address the need to create a debt management policy
and strategy which may include creating a professional debt management office,
reform the legal, institutional and administrative framework, and adopt best
practices in public debt management.
End
No comments:
Post a Comment